Reality Check: What Happens When Political Parties Actually Try to Work Together
Political rhetoric consistently celebrates bipartisanship as a democratic virtue, yet scholarly attention to this phenomenon remains surprisingly limited. While politicians routinely invoke the need for “reaching across the aisle” and “working together,” the actual mechanics of bipartisan cooperation and its relationship to legislative success present a complex puzzle that deserves systematic investigation. This post explores tensions between theoretical expectations about bipartisan legislation and observed patterns in the legislative process, particularly focusing on how negative agenda control might shape the fate of cross-party coalitions.
Defining Bipartisanship and Its Patterns
Bipartisanship, in its most straightforward definition, involves cooperation between members of opposing political parties on legislative matters. This cooperation can manifest in various forms: co-sponsorship of bills, collaborative amendment processes, joint committee work, or coordinated floor advocacy. However, the mere presence of members from both parties supporting a measure does not necessarily constitute meaningful bipartisanship, as the nature and extent of cross-party involvement can vary dramatically.
The conditions under which bipartisan cooperation emerges warrant closer examination. Conventional wisdom suggests that regional and local issues might be more conducive to cross-party collaboration, as they often transcend ideological divides and focus on concrete benefits for specific constituencies. Infrastructure projects, disaster relief, and geographically concentrated economic issues might create natural opportunities for bipartisan coalition-building. Yet systematic evidence for these patterns remains limited, leaving important questions about the scope conditions for bipartisan cooperation unanswered.
The Signaling Function of Bipartisan Support
A critical question for legislative scholars concerns whether bipartisan bills enjoy advantages in the legislative process. Does cross-party sponsorship signal broad acceptability and increase the likelihood of passage? The signaling theory would suggest that bipartisan support provides information to uncommitted legislators about a bill’s mainstream appeal and potential electoral safety. This signal might be particularly valuable in an era of heightened partisan polarization, where legislators face strong incentives to oppose initiatives associated with the opposing party.
However, the relationship between bipartisan sponsorship and legislative success may be more complex than simple signaling models suggest. The signal provided by cross-party support depends heavily on the credibility and representativeness of the participating legislators. Bipartisan support from ideological moderates might carry different informational content than cooperation between party leaders or members from safe districts.
Limitations of the Pivotal Politics Model
The pivotal politics model, developed by Keith Krehbiel, offers a preference-based account of legislative outcomes that focuses on the ideological positions of key actors—particularly the median voter, filibuster pivots, and veto players. According to this model, legislation passes when it falls within the “gridlock interval” defined by these pivotal actors’ preferences. Bills that satisfy a sufficiently broad coalition, spanning from the most liberal to the most conservative supporters, should overcome procedural hurdles and achieve passage.
The model’s predictions about bipartisan legislation appear straightforward: bills with sponsors spanning a wide ideological range—particularly those covering or exceeding the gridlock interval—should reliably reach the floor and pass into law. The diversity of sponsorship should signal that the legislation appeals to a broad enough coalition to overcome potential filibusters and vetoes.
Yet empirical patterns suggest that this preference-based account may be incomplete. Bipartisan bills that seemingly satisfy the pivotal politics model’s conditions for passage sometimes fail to reach the floor for a vote, while others that do reach the floor may encounter unexpected difficulties. This gap between theoretical expectations and observed outcomes points to factors beyond simple preference alignment that influence legislative success.
The Role of Negative Agenda Control
Cartel theory, as developed by Gary Cox and Mathew McCubbins, offers an alternative perspective on legislative organization that emphasizes the role of party leaders in controlling the legislative agenda. Under this theory, the majority party operates as a cartel that seeks to advance its collective interests by controlling which bills receive floor consideration. This control extends beyond simply promoting the majority party’s preferred policies to include preventing the minority party from achieving legislative victories that might enhance its electoral prospects.
Negative agenda control represents the aggressive application of cartel theory’s logic: the majority party uses its procedural powers not merely to advance its own agenda, but to actively deny the minority party opportunities for legislative success. This strategy recognizes that political competition involves both positive-sum policy-making and zero-sum battles over credit and blame attribution.
The implications for bipartisan legislation are profound. Even when cross-party bills satisfy the preference conditions outlined by pivotal politics models, they may be blocked if majority party leaders perceive them as providing political benefits to minority party members. A successful bipartisan initiative might allow minority party legislators to claim credit for policy achievements, potentially undermining the majority party’s electoral advantages.
Barriers to Bipartisan Cooperation
Understanding what prevents more frequent bipartisan cooperation requires examining both structural and strategic factors. At the structural level, increasing ideological polarization between parties may reduce the natural overlap in policy preferences that facilitates cooperation. Geographic sorting and primary election dynamics might further incentivize partisan positioning over cross-party collaboration.
Strategic considerations add another layer of complexity. In a political environment where parties compete for credit and blame attribution, cooperation with the opposing party carries inherent risks. Legislators might fear that bipartisan collaboration signals ideological weakness to their base supporters or provides political cover for opponents’ policy positions.
The question of whether these barriers operate differently for national versus local issues deserves particular attention. Local and regional matters might offer more opportunities for bipartisan cooperation because they often involve distributive benefits rather than ideological positioning. However, even seemingly local issues can become nationalized in contemporary politics, potentially reducing the scope for cross-party collaboration.
Research Questions and Future Directions
This analysis raises several questions that warrant systematic empirical investigation. First, what are the actual patterns of success and failure for bipartisan legislation compared to partisan initiatives? Do bipartisan bills face different procedural hurdles, and if so, under what conditions?
Second, how do party leaders decide which bipartisan initiatives to support or obstruct? What factors influence the strategic calculations that determine when negative agenda control is employed against cross-party coalitions?
Third, what are the long-term consequences of negative agenda control for democratic governance? Does the systematic obstruction of bipartisan initiatives affect public trust in institutions, legislators’ willingness to cooperate, or the overall effectiveness of the policy-making process?
Finally, how do these dynamics vary across different types of issues, institutional settings, and political contexts? Understanding the scope conditions for bipartisan cooperation and its obstruction could inform both theoretical models and practical efforts to enhance legislative effectiveness.
The success or failure of bipartisan lawmaking carries implications that extend far beyond the immediate policy outcomes. Legislative victories provide parties with opportunities to shape political narratives, demonstrate governing competence, and build electoral coalitions. When bipartisan bills succeed, they can alter the political landscape by creating new policy frameworks, establishing precedents for future cooperation, or shifting public expectations about governmental effectiveness.
Conversely, the systematic obstruction of bipartisan initiatives might contribute to public cynicism about political institutions and reduce incentives for future cross-party cooperation. If legislators learn that bipartisan efforts face systematic disadvantages in the legislative process, they may become less willing to invest in building cross-party coalitions.
The agenda-setting implications are equally significant. Control over which issues receive legislative attention allows parties to shape public discourse and political priorities. By blocking bipartisan initiatives, majority parties can prevent certain issues from gaining prominence in national political debates, potentially limiting the minority party’s ability to highlight neglected problems or alternative policy approaches.